What relationship, if
any, consistently holds between interest rates and private savings
behaviour? Do savings really go up when interest rates go up? And can
excessively high savings ratios be brought down by keeping interest
rates low? If so, what rates, and how low? And if savings rates stay
high regardless does that mean we're in some sort of liquidity trap?
I should probably have
had this down decades ago when I first encountered an ISLM graph, but
the truth is that I've never met anyone in the market who actually
uses ISLM analysis. Or mentions it.
Instead I have focussed
on private cashflows and savings behaviour, usually looking at
private sector savings surpluses and tracking their impact on bond
yields. For emerging markets, this is often crucial: the most
powerful financial dynamic bar none in emerging markets is what
happens to government bond yields when a private sector savings
deficit flips over into a surplus, or vice versa. In these cases, the
cashflows are easy to trace: if an economy develops a savings
surplus, then on a net basis, the private sector is dumping cash into
a financial sector which, by definition, can use it to buy only
government bonds or foreign assets. Hence bond prices rise and
yields fall. Easy money.
Even in the
massively-open and highly disintermediated financial system of the
US, traces of the relationship remain.
Interesting though this
is, it's hardly a complete theory linking bond yields with savings
behaviour. Nor would one expect it to be: if private sector savings
surpluses and deficits were the only determinant of bond yields, the
world wouldn't have so many fixed income economists (and professional
Fed watchers). And the financial world would never had heard of 'fair
value models' for bond yields.
So let's look at those
models. In my experience these fair value models regress and
regularly recalibrate from three factors:
- policy rates
- inflation rates
- growth rates
A movement, or an
expected/forecast movement in any one of these will change what the
model signals to be the 'fair value' of a bond.
Anything that regresses
and recalibrates enough will end up looking like it has useful
explanatory power. Here's how my simple fair-value model of US bond
yields compares with what actually happened over the last 21 years.
It's not a superb fit, and even if it was, that would be testament
simply to the power of serial recalibration rather than the theory it
allegedly sets out to test.
Nonetheless, the
conclusions which we can draw from this model are remarkably similar
to those wrested from doubtless far more sophisticated models
produced by our august Wall Street friends. And so are the
conclusions are drawn by comparing actual bond yields with 'fair
value' yields. What screams out in retrospect is that during
2004-2008 bond yields were far lower than 'fair value'. And from
there it is but a step to conclude that the chief reason for that was
that policy rates were set too low for too long, and, moreover, were
expected to be kept too low for longer still. The graph serves as the
charge-sheet against Alan Greenspan. And as it looks as if the same
thing is happening again now (bond yields far lower than 'justified'
by likely economic growth and inflation), we might eventually find it
thrown into evidence against Ben Bernanke at some later date.
What the chart is
saying right now is simple: bond yields are simply too low, making
bonds an unattractive investment. Let's put it even more bluntly:
who in their right minds would save to invest in bonds right now? At
which point, we get to ask (and answer) an important question –
regardless of the absolute nominal bond yield, does sufficiently 'bad
value' in bond yields usually dissuade saving, and do sufficiently
'generous' bond yields usually encourage saving?
And I think we can
answer than question empirically with a simple 'Yes'.
Consider the
relationship between the deviation of bond yields from fair-value,
and movements in the private sector savings surplus. The chart below
illustrates it well, and that's not just because I've fiddled the
axes. More importantly, the correlation between sequential movements
in these two during the last 87 observations passes the 1%
significance level quite easily.
For those of us
interested in recent US economic history, and in global
savings/investment imbalances, this chart is pretty irresistible, as
it links the descent into major private sector savings deficit during
1997-2000 and again in 2005-2007 with bond yields being somehow
maintained at levels which actively discouraged saving. When yields
rose (relative to 'fair value') savings deficits were trimmed and
reversed.
And now? Bonds
represent absolutely rotten value, and as long as this is the case,
the US private sector savings surplus will continue to decline,
boosting US consumer demand at a pace slightly exceeding those of
private sector income growth (widely defined).
One more thing:
there is absolutely no sign of a Keynesian 'liquidity trap' anywhere
on this chart.
No comments:
Post a Comment