“And now China's
slowing, I don't see any spark for growth anywhere in the world,”
lamented a friend last night. My friend is right to be worried,
because he runs a string of listed mining companies. Which puts him
in the same situation as Australians, Middle Eastern oil-producers
and . . . virtually nobody else. For the rest of us, the fact that
China is slowing is almost unreservedly good news. Unfortunately,
our imaginations are so locked-in to the model that emerging markets
growth is the only hope for the world, we cannot see what is plainly
obvious.
China is the marginal
buyer – the price setter – for every major commodity in the
world. When China slows, commodity prices fall. When commodity prices
fall:
- households everywhere in the world (with the exceptions noted above) get an immediate boost to real incomes,
- non-commodity producing countries get a lift in their terms of trade, and
- corporates in those countries get some immediate relief from margin pressure.
All this is obvious,
and is already showing up in the data.
In a global economy
suffering from stagnant demand in over-leveraged developed economies,
there could be no better news. Falling commodity prices are
identical to an unexpected one-off bonus, or an income tax refund.
Nominal incomes may be rising very slowly, if at all, but as
gasoline prices fall, real incomes are boosted. That means either
non-gasoline consumption can rise, or household balance sheets can be
fixed faster without cutting into non-gasoline consumption.
But there's more. Don't
imagine this works only for the West: these dynamics work as well
inside China as elsewhere. Falling commodity prices, if passed
on to the consumer, boost real household incomes there too. When
China slows, the headline numbers tell us that China's imports growth
slows sharply. And if China's import growth slows, doesn't that mean
that Western hopes of exporting to China slow with it? Not at all:
it means commodity-producers' hopes of exporting to China slow. If
you are exporting goods or services to China's household sector,
it's probably either a wash, or a modest positive (as Chinese
household incomes, and corporate margins improve).
Now let's see how this
is playing out in the data. The big shock of the week, and the one
which unlocks the key to most of the rest of the week's data, was
China's imports for June: they fell 8.6% mom – a fall 1.3SDs
below seasonal historic trends which was sufficiently bad fully to
reverse May's gains. China's imports fell because of collapsing
commodities buying: in volume terms crude oil fell 14.8% mom (lowest
volume since Dec); refined products fell 15.6% mom (lowest since
Sept); iron ore fell 8.7% (lowest since April); copper fell 17.5% mom
(lowest since Aug). By country, the biggest loser was Australia, down
17.5% mom.
(Withdrawal on this
scale by the marginal buyer, if sustained, is most unlikely to be
properly reflected in prices yet. We have yet to discover just how
much untracked and undisclosed commodity inventories are meandering
aimlessly around the world's oceans, sitting it out and waiting for
an upturn before docking.)
But now let's look at
the data outside China. First of all, let's look at terms of trade, where the story is unambiguous:
- US import prices fell 2.7% mom in June, whilst export prices fell 1.7% mom, so terms of trade rose 1% mom. Over the last three months US terms of trade have gained 2.2%.
- Korean import prices fell 3.6% mom in June, whilst export prices fell 3.6%, so terms of trade rose 2% during June. In the three months to June they improved by 5.3%.
- Taiwan import prices fell 2.2% mom in June, whilst export prices fell 0.7%, so Taiwan's terms of trade improved 1.6% mom. That takes the improvement over the last three months to 3.6%.
- In Europe, the
latest data we have is Germany's data for May: they show import
prices down 0.7%, whilst export prices fell only 0.1%, so terms of
trade rose 0.6%. Since March, however, they have now risen 1.3%, and
we should expect a similar trajectory in June.
Improvement in the
terms of trade in the short term (ie, before the change in relative
prices affects other economic choices) a boost to trade balances,
which in turn implies greater liquidity in the economy, and improved
cashflows into the banking system (which turned up, for example, in
China's June money data).
The same transfer in relative pricing power is also showing
up in the change in producers and wholesalers prices, in a way which
demonstrates the potential relief to operating margins:
- In Japan, the Domestic Corporate Goods Price Index showed raw materials down 3.7% mom, but intermediates by 0.8%, and final goods down only 0.5%.
- In S Korea, the PPI fell 1.4% mom, led by agricultural products. Outside those, however, chemical, petroluem and petrochemicals and basic metals fell most steeply, whilst electronics rose 0.5% mom and vehicles 0.4%.
- In Taiwan, the WPI fell 1.2% mom, but with raw materials down 6.2%, intermediates up 0.1% and finished goods up 0.6%.
- In Germany, the WPI fell 1.1% mom in June, and although the full data-set is not available, it is clear from what data is available that the fall was led by fuel costs.
- In France, May's PPI fell 1.1%, mainly because of a 5.3% fall in coke and refined products, but prices of manufacturing products fell only 0.7%.
- Even in inflation-prone Turkey, the PPI fell 1.5% mom in June, as crude petroleum /gas fell 8.6% mom and agriculturals fell 6.1%, whilst manufacturing goods prices fell only 0.75%.
- In the US, the story is slightly different, in that most unexpectedly, the PPI did not deflate in June, but rather rose 0.1% mom. But even here the margins story is the same: crude goods fell 3.6% mom, intermediates fell 0.5%, and finished goods rose 0.1%.
So margins,
cashflows and financial systems are getting relief from the falling
commodity prices which the Chinese slowdown is precipitating.
But will this boost
to the corporate and financial sectors also, crucially, be passed on
to the household sector? By the end of 2011, gasoline and energy
spending accounted for 4% of US household consumption, and almost
certainly more in a Europe where – inexplicably, irresponsibly and
regressively - government policies assume and usually encourage
ever-rising real fuel prices. Rather than worry about the slowdown in China, Western economists should worry about Western
governments not allowing the pricing benefits of that slowdown to
pass to their household sectors.
On current showing, such stupidity
must class as the default setting.
No comments:
Post a Comment