In fact, movements in these gaps during 1Q tell us a great deal about China’s current position and policy choices. They are suggesting that:
- China has had a degree of success in stemming the outflow of cash which peaked in 3Q15 and 4Q15, but also
- With most domestic savings avenues currently closed or discredited (equities, deposits, wealth management products, P2P vehicles), the flow of excess private savings are necessarily being pushed out of financial assets and into real assets, including real estate (again) and commodities (again).
If so, the conclusion is clear: the need for financial sector reform in order to deal with the savings surplus remains urgent, because the lack of viable savings vehicles not only generates bubbles in non-financial assets, but simultaneously puts pressure on PBOC to supply the liquidity private savers no longer wish to entrust to the vehicles available.
Last week brought two pieces of news from which to judge whether the flow of cash out of China seen since the middle of 2014 has been successfully checked. First, foreign reserves rose by US$6.4bn in April to US$6.4bn to US$3.219tr, the second consecutive monthly rise following 18 months of nearly-uninterrupted decline. Second, China’s 1Q current account balance was announced to have been a US$48.1bn surplus, which was roughly in line with what was expected in the light of 1Q’s US$125.7bn trade surplus, although down by US$37.2bn yoy.
The balance of payment data ought, in theory, be the place to start to assess whether the rush of cash out of China has been checked. And on the face of it, the situation is encouraging: China reported a current account surplus of US$48.1bn in 1Q, with a goods trade surplus of US$104.9bn partly offset by a services deficit of US$57bn, and with net international income receipts of US$1.9bn almost fully offset by the US$1.7bn recorded in net transfers out of China. On this accounting, the current account surplus was equivalent to 2% of GDP in 1Q, with 12m surplus retreating go 2.7% in 1Q from the 3% recorded in 4Q15.
But the preliminary estimates also reported that the capital and financial accounts ran a US$48.1bn, completely offsetting the current account surplus. As a result, we should have expected no change in China’s foreign reserves during 1Q. But the reserves data shows China’s reserves fell US$117.8bn in the 3m to March.
The gap between the balance of payments data and the movement in reserves can be seen as one measure of the size and direction of movements of cash and capital into and out of China without attracting the attention of China’s central authorities. When China’s economy is under stress, this gets glossed as ‘capital flight’; when times are good, it tends to just get called ‘hot money’. In most countries, these differences tend to get logged under ‘errors and omissions.’ In China, however, the amounts involved are now so large that such ‘errors and omissions’ would be the biggest line item in the balance of payments.
Between 2005 and the middle of 2014, this difference was almost always sharply positive; since the middle of 2014, when the dollar surged, the difference has always been sharply negative. This reached a peak in 3Q15 and 4Q15, with deficits ot US$243.1bn and US$225.1bn respectively. In that context, the US$117.8bn missing from the accounts in 1Q16 is an improvement. But the unacknowledged outflow is only moderated, not yet checked or reversed.
The mild rises in foreign reserves during March and April suggest that the situation continues to improve.
With all its faults, if one takes China’s current account data at face value we can do a second check, by comparing movements in China’s private sector savings surplus to the net flow of cash into (or out of) China’s banking system. The theory here is that if the private sector is generating a net flow of savings after having done all the consumption and investment it intends, the result is must be a flow of cash into the financial system. By definition, the financial system can use that cashflow only to buy public sector or foreign assets.
During 1Q, the current account showed a surplus of 2% of GDP, whilst the government was also running a fiscal surplus equivalent to 0.6% of GDP (down from 2.4% in 1Q15). As a result, China’s private sector surplus can in a 1.4% of GDP, up from 1.1% in 1Q15, and stabilizing the 12m PSSS at 6.4% of GDP.
- In Rmb terms, the 1Q PSSS surplus amounted to Rmb 220.8bn, and the 12m surplus came to Rmb4,400bn..
- In 1Q, banks saw a net inflow of deposits of Rmb 813bn, but during the 12m, there was a net outflow of Rmb4,731bn.
In the 12m to March, the gap between the surplus savings generated (Rmb 4,400bn) and the net outflow of cash from the banking system (Rmb4,731bn) came to Rmb9,131bn. Taking an average Rmb rate of 6.32 for the period, that is an amount equivalent to US$1.445tr. Meanwhile, the amount ‘missing’ from difference between the balance of payments and movements in reserves comes to US$653bn. In other words, the balance of payments and reserves data may yet be understating the extent of capital outflow, quite considerably.
This is not the only explanation, however: deposits can rise in the absence of bank lending if the private sector becomes a net seller of non-financial assets (such as property) and banks the proceeds. Conversely, deposits can grow more slowly than lending if the private sector becomes a net buyer of non-financial assets, such as property or commodities. During 1Q, the turnaround in real estate markets in first and second tier cities has been marked, and the recovery in China’s commodity markets has been strong enough to prompt concern among regulators of China’s commodity futures’ market.
At this point, it is surely clear that it is dangerous to reach firm conclusions. However, the balance of evidence suggests that the peak of capital outflow from China has probably been reached, but that China’s savers have yet to be persuaded that the products and services available to savers (deposits, equities, bonds, wealth management products) offer acceptable rates of return. Consequently, the hunt is redoubled for real domestic assets in which to invest the surplus savings the economy continues to generate.
The case for continued financial reform could hardly be more obvious.
No comments:
Post a Comment